Just like in constitutional law, if you link judicial review solely to political malfunction, there's always some of that, so you'd be reviewing everything. Likewise with contracts. If all we were looking for was a market malfunction, we'd always be able to find some.
if any of our employees injure someone through negligence, the tenant exculpates them; and if anyone sues for negligence and wins, the tenant indemnifies Standard Oil
The court decides this can't be enforced. Why would Standard Oil put those provisions in? It's not like the tenant is going to have a lot of money. Maybe to head off lawsuits before they eveng get started. But maybe there's something more subtle at work here, and Standard Oil has a good economic reason for allocating the risk to the station operator.
If the court strikes down these clauses as unconscionable, have they solved the market malfunction? No: the market power disparity can just relocate to other terms of the contract.
Contracts are a tool for allocating risks. Let's say that our lease has the following parameters: rent, and a risk clause (exculpatory/indemnifying clauses). The tenant has an upper limit of $500. The landlord has perfectly discriminating monopolistic power: they draft the contract, and they are in a position to extract the max from the tenant.
In Case 2, the landlord will let the tenant bear the risk (i.e., there will be a risk clause), and the rent will be $480. That's how the landlord maximizes the benefit (i.e., extracts the full $500).
In case 1A, the rent is $500 and there's a risk clause. Because the tenant doesn't know they're going over their limit.
So when we're looking for unconscionability, it is not enough merely to look for the presence of a risk clause. You also need to look at price. See the Bethlehem Steel case cited in Weaver (that was about steel for WWI, although the date on the case makes it look like WWII... litigation can be slow).
Then we'd look at state statutes. And precedent.
And from the statute, we'd get the "unless unreasonable" language. Now we've got a nice squishy word that lends itself to litigation.
From cases, we see that in 2 cases intermediate appellate courts did what we want (truck parking and sattelite dish placement). In both of those cases, plaintiffs got judicial review: not just that the restrictions can't be unreasonable, but also that the courts will decide.
Now we have a pretty good case: the cats are inside the condo and they are quiet. We're not imposing anything on others.
But how much judicial review will we really get?
We already know that the people who made the initial covenants were imperfect decision-makers. But we need to ask ourselves whether the courts are better.
First Wolff
Now if one person can get out of the restriction, they get all of the benefits of the collective restriction, and none of the burden. So there's not much to infer from the fact that one person wants to get out of the restriction. The restrictions on the corner lots make them buffers: they insulate the rest of the parcels from the influx of businesses there. Those lots are worth less, but the developer thought that was a good plan, because it made all the other lots more valuable.
So is this a good candidate for getting rid of the restriction?
Well, it's a close case, and the presence of a dissent makes it clear that there are differences of opinion.
So the court does remove the restriction, but that was probably not even necessary.